As Kawan Patel suggested on LabourList a few days ago, New
Labour was founded on the idea that while Margaret Thatcher might not have
‘saved the nation’ as her Conservative supporters claim, there were things she
‘got right’. I believe that this focus on the specifics of the Thatcherite
legacy, such as privatisation and reductions in union power, is wrong. It is
what was entirely responsible for New Labour’s failure to reverse inequality
and for allowing a massive financial bubble to replace a sustainable industrial
infrastructure in Britain. We must learn this lesson.
For a start, the image of 1970s Labour government in hapless
thrall to left-wing union leaders leading their unwilling rank-and-file members
to destroy the British economy is almost entirely a creation of the press and
Conservative myth-makers. The root cause of the industrial unrest of the 1970s
that culminated in the ‘Winter of Discontent’ of 1978-79 was consistent annual
inflation in double digits. This was mainly as a consequence of massive hikes
in the price of oil. Firms showed no restraint in allowing their prices to rise
to maintain their profits; for workers to maintain their standards of living
required credible threats to withdraw labour. In doing this they were, on
average, successful – but no more than that. In relation to labour
productivity, hourly wages were at exactly the same point in 1979 as they had
been in 1972 (See Figure 1).
![]() |
Figure 1: Labour Productivity in UK. From Pessoa and Van Reenen 2012, Decoupling of Wage Growth and Productivity Growth? Myth and Reality. Sources ONS, OECD. |
There were a record number of days lost to labour disputes in
1979, yet this amounted to only just over one day per worker. These disputes
were often unofficial, initiated by local militants or groups of workers whose
earnings were low, as they are today, despite the importance or unpleasant
conditions of their jobs. They were not in general the consequence of ‘union
barons’ seeking to usurp the government of the day. While causing inconvenience,
sometimes unpleasantly so, industrial action did not even have a significant
effect on the economy as a whole. National output fell slightly in the first
quarter of 1979, after what was in any case a harsh winter. But it roared back
in the second quarter of that year to be bang on the rising trend for the
decade as Mrs Thatcher first took office. And this was to be its peak until the
second quarter of 1983, by which time unemployment had doubled (See Figure 2). In economic
terms, far from saving the nation, Mrs Thatcher’s government appears to have
laid waste to it! Yet, thanks to the Falklands war and the UK electoral system,
this same government was returned to office that year with a huge majority on
only 42% of the popular vote.
![]() |
Figure 2: Real GDP in £millions 1970 – 1984. Source ONS
|
Cherry-picking policies that seemed ‘to work’, whether
Thatcherite in origin or more social democratic, without an overarching
understanding and commitment, is precisely what led New Labour to ultimate
failure. Thatcherism was much clearer. We can see this in a recent quote
from the Margaret Thatcher Foundation for Freedom’s senior research fellow:
There was never any reason to believe that governments – which are just small collections of individuals – would have the necessary wisdom to make better decisions than the market – a much larger collection of individuals.
This is pure Friedrich Hayek, and pure nonsense as an
approach to economic governance in a properly-functioning democracy, but it
served well in guiding the Conservatives toward their chosen constituency. The
case for markets is twofold: firstly free exchange of goods and services is
fulfilling in its own right; secondly under certain circumstances the
distributions that result from free exchange cannot be unequivocally bettered.
These circumstances are quite restrictive: equality of initial resources and
access to the market, complete information about the goods and services
exchanged and clearly-formed preferences. They sound unrealistic and they are –
so, most of the time, to let the market decide is as much as a decision by
government as to try to adjust or over-ride its outcome. Moreover, a government
is only ‘a small collection of individuals’ in a dictatorship (whether of an
elite based on political or economic power). An effective democracy, to a
greater or lesser extent, involves all who vote or express an opinion that
reaches policymakers - almost all those in fact who take part in the market.
What is more, each individual has, in principle, equal weight in this process,
whereas weighting in the market always occurs by wealth. If we want better economic
outcomes, therefore, we should look at least as much to improvements in the way
democratic processes balance individual and collective voices as to ways of
mimicking market mechanisms.
The lessons Labour should learn from the Thatcher experience are
not specifics to do with trade union power or privatisation but more general
lessons. Unbuffered fanaticism is dangerous for society and the economy, and while
the market should certainly be embraced it can have no automatic primacy for
determining fair, or even efficient, outcomes. In policy terms this means
improving the workings of democracy to widen the range of voices heard, being clear
about the merits and limits of markets, and being willing to make intelligent
and informed interventions where these limits bind.
No comments:
Post a Comment